How the Law of Supply Explains the Trade-Offs of Opportunity Cost

The law of supply is a fundamental principle of economics that states that, all else being equal, as the price of a good or service increases, the quantity supplied of that good or service also increases. Conversely, as the price of a good or service decreases, the quantity supplied of that good or service also decreases. This means that there is a positive relationship between price and quantity supplied: producers are willing to offer more of their products for sale when they can charge higher prices for them.

Opportunity cost is another important concept in economics that refers to the value of the next best alternative that is forgone as a result of making a choice. It represents the benefits that could have been obtained by choosing a different option. For example, if you have $100 and you can either buy a new pair of shoes or invest it in the stock market, the opportunity cost of buying the shoes is the potential return you could have earned from investing the money.

The law of supply and opportunity cost are closely related because they both reflect the trade-offs that producers face when they allocate their scarce resources. By choosing to produce more of one good or service, they are giving up the chance to produce more of another good or service. The opportunity cost of increasing the quantity supplied of a product is the value of the other products that could have been produced instead.

How to Calculate Opportunity Cost Using the Law of Supply

One way to measure the opportunity cost of producing more of a good or service is to use the slope of the supply curve. The supply curve is a graphical representation of the law of supply that shows how much quantity supplied changes in response to changes in price. The slope of the supply curve indicates how much producers are willing to increase or decrease their output for a given change in price.

The formula for calculating the slope of a supply curve is:

���������=���������ℎ���������������������������ℎ�����������textSlope=fractextChangeinQuantitySuppliedtextChangeinPrice

The slope of a supply curve can also be interpreted as the marginal cost of production, which is the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of output. Marginal cost reflects the opportunity cost of using more resources to produce more output.

For example, suppose that a farmer can produce either wheat or corn on his land. The supply curve for wheat is given by:

��=100+2��QW​=100+2PW​

where ��QW​ is the quantity supplied of wheat in tons and ��PW​ is the price of wheat in dollars per ton.

The slope of this supply curve is:

���������=���������ℎ���������������������������ℎ�����������=����21=2textSlope=fractextChangeinQuantitySuppliedtextChangeinPrice=frac21=2

This means that for every $1 increase in the price of wheat, the farmer is willing to produce 2 more tons of wheat. It also means that the marginal cost of producing one more ton of wheat is $0.5.

Now suppose that the farmer can also produce corn on his land. The supply curve for corn is given by:

��=50+��QC​=50+PC​

where ��QC​ is the quantity supplied of corn in tons and ��PC​ is the price of corn in dollars per ton.

The slope of this supply curve is:

���������=���������ℎ���������������������������ℎ�����������=����11=1textSlope=fractextChangeinQuantitySuppliedtextChangeinPrice=frac11=1

This means that for every $1 increase in the price of corn, the farmer is willing to produce 1 more ton of corn. It also means that the marginal cost of producing one more ton of corn is $1.

To calculate the opportunity cost of producing more wheat, we need to compare how much corn output is sacrificed for each additional ton of wheat output. This can be done by using the slopes of both supply curves:

�������������������=����������������ℎ����������������������������������������=����21=2textOpportunityCost=fractextSlopeofWheatSupplyCurvetextSlopeofCornSupplyCurve=frac21=2

This means that for every additional ton of wheat produced, 2 tons of corn are forgone. In other words, producing one more ton of wheat costs 2 tons of corn.

Similarly, to calculate the opportunity cost of producing more corn, we need to compare how much wheat output is sacrificed for each additional ton of corn output. This can be done by using the slopes of both supply curves:

�������������������=������������������������������������������ℎ��������������=����12=0.5textOpportunityCost=fractextSlopeofCornSupplyCurvetextSlopeofWheatSupplyCurve=frac12=0.5

This means that for every additional ton of corn produced, 0.5 tons of wheat are forgone. In other words, producing one more ton of corn costs 0.5 tons of wheat.

How the Law of Supply and Opportunity Cost Affect Decision Making

The law of supply and opportunity cost can help producers make optimal decisions about how to allocate their resources and what products to produce. Producers will choose to produce the product that has the highest profit potential, which depends on both the price and the opportunity cost of production.

Profit is calculated by subtracting the total cost of production from the total revenue of sales. Total cost includes both explicit costs, which are the direct monetary payments made to acquire resources, and implicit costs, which are the opportunity costs of using owned resources. Total revenue is calculated by multiplying the price of the product by the quantity sold.

The formula for calculating profit is:

����������=����������������−�������������textProfit=textTotalRevenue−textTotalCost

To maximize profit, producers will choose the level of output where the marginal revenue of producing one more unit is equal to the marginal cost of producing one more unit. Marginal revenue is the additional revenue generated by selling one more unit of output. Marginal cost is the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of output, which also reflects the opportunity cost of using more resources.

The formula for calculating marginal revenue is:

�������������������=���������ℎ�����������������������ℎ������������������textMarginalRevenue=fractextChangeinTotalRevenuetextChangeinQuantitySold

The formula for calculating marginal cost is:

����������������=���������ℎ��������������������ℎ����������������������textMarginalCost=fractextChangeinTotalCosttextChangeinQuantityProduced

To maximize profit, producers will set:

�������������������=����������������textMarginalRevenue=textMarginalCost

This condition ensures that producers are not leaving any potential profit on the table by producing too little or too much output.

For example, suppose that a farmer can produce either wheat or corn on his land, and that the market prices for wheat and corn are $10 and $8 per ton respectively. The farmer’s supply curves for wheat and corn are given by:

��=100+2��QW​=100+2PW​

��=50+��QC​=50+PC​

The farmer’s marginal revenue curves for wheat and corn are given by:

���=10MRW​=10

���=8MRC​=8

The farmer’s marginal cost curves for wheat and corn are given by:

���=0.5��−50MCW​=0.5QW​−50

���=��−50MCC​=QC​−50

To find the optimal level of output for wheat, we set:

���=���MRW​=MCW​

Substituting the values, we get:

10=0.5��−5010=0.5QW​−50

Solving for ��QW​, we get:

��∗=120QW∗​=120

This means that the farmer should produce 120 tons of wheat to maximize his profit from wheat production.

To find the optimal level of output for corn, we set:

���=���MRC​=MCC​

Substituting the values, we get:

8=��−508=QC​−50

Solving for ��QC​, we get:

��∗=58QC∗​=58

This means that the farmer should produce 58 tons of corn to maximize his profit from corn production.

To find the total profit from producing both wheat and corn, we need to calculate the total revenue and total cost for each product and add them up.

The total revenue from wheat production is:

���=����∗=(10)(120)=1200TRW​=PW​QW∗​=(10)(120)=1200

The total revenue from corn production is:

���=����∗=(8)(58)=464TRC​=PC​QC∗​=(8)(58)=464

The total cost of wheat production is:

���=�����∗+50��∗=(0.5��−50)��∗+50��∗=(0.5)(120)2−(50)(120)+(50)(120)=3600−6000+6000=3600TCW​=MCW​QW∗​+50QW∗​=(0.5QW​−50)QW∗​+50QW∗​=(0.5)(120)2−(50)(120)+(50)(120)=3600−6000+6000=3600

The total cost of corn production is:

���=�����∗+50��∗=(��−50)��∗+50��∗=(58)2−(50)(58)+(50)(58)=3364−2900+2900=3364TCC​=MCC​QC∗​+50QC∗​=(QC​−50)QC∗​+50QC∗​=(58)2−(50)(58)+(50)(58)=3364−2900+2900=3364

The total profit from producing both wheat and corn is:

����������=���+���−���−���=(1200+textProfit=TRW​+TRC​−TCW​−TCC​=(1200+

Doms Desk

Leave a Comment